ECON 306 — Microeconomic Analysis
  • Syllabus
  • Schedule
  • Content
  • Assignments
  • Resources

4.1 — Modeling Firms With Market Power — Appendix

  • Overview
  • Appendices
    • Appendix 1.2
    • Appendix 1.3
    • Appendix 1.4
    • Appendix 2.2
    • Appendix 2.3
    • Appendix 2.4
    • Appendix 2.5
    • Appendix 2.6
    • Appendix 4.1
  • Math Review Guide
    • Functions
    • Graphing Linear Equations
    • Rates of Change
    • Nonlinear Functions & Optimization
    • Solving Systems of (Linear) Equations
    • Exponents & Logarithms
  • Computing Guides
    • How to Make a PDF
  • Advice
    • Tips for Success
  • Quotes About Economics

On this page

  • Monopolists Only Produce Where Demand is Elastic: Proof
  • Derivation of the Lerner Index
  • Firms With Market Power vs. Competitive Firms’ Responses to Market Changes

4.1 — Modeling Firms With Market Power — Appendix

Monopolists Only Produce Where Demand is Elastic: Proof

Let’s first show the relationship between \(MR(q)\) and price elasticity of demand, \(\epsilon_D\).

\[\begin{align*} MR(q) &= p+\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\bigg)q && \text{Definition of } MR(q)\\ \frac{MR(q)}{p} &= \frac{p}{p}+\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\bigg) \frac{q}{p} && \text{Dividing both sides by } p\\ \frac{MR(q)}{p} &= 1+\underbrace{\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\times \frac{q}{p} \bigg)}_{\frac{1}{\epsilon}} && \text{Simplifying}\\ \frac{MR(q)}{p} &= 1+\frac{1}{\epsilon_D} && \text{Recognize price elasticity } \epsilon_D=\frac{\Delta q}{\Delta p} \times \frac{p}{q}\\ MR(q) &= p\bigg(1+\frac{1}{\epsilon_D}\bigg) && \text{Multiplying both sides by }p\\ \end{align*}\]

Remember, we’ve simplified \(\epsilon_D = \frac{1}{slope} \times \frac{p}{q}\), where \(\frac{1}{slope} = \frac{\Delta q}{\Delta p}\) because on a demand curve, \(slope = \frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\).

Now that we have this alternate expression for \(MR(q)\), lets assume \(MC(q) \geq 0\) and set them equal to one another to maximize profits:

\[\begin{align*} MR(q) &= MC(q)\\ p(1+\frac{1}{\epsilon_D}) & = MC(q)\\ p(1-\frac{1}{|\epsilon_D|}) & = MC(q)\\ \end{align*}\]

I rearrange the last line only to remind us that \(\epsilon_D\) is always negative!

Now note the following:

  • If \(|\epsilon_D| < 1\), then \(MR(q)\) is negative. Since \(MC(q)\) is assumed to be positive, it cannot equal a negative \(MR(q)\), hence this is not profit-maximizing.
  • If \(|\epsilon_D| = 1\), then \(MR(q)\) is 0. Only if \(MC(q)\) is also 0 is this profit-maximizing.
  • If \(|\epsilon_D| > 1\), then \(MR(q)\) is positive. It can equal a positive \(MC(q)\) to be profit-maximizing.

Hence, a monopolist will never produce in the inelastic region of the demand curve (where \(MR(q)<0)\), and will only produce at the unit elastic part of the demand curve (where \(MR(q)=0)\) if \(MC(q)=0\). Thus, it generally produces in the elastic region where \(MR(q)>0\).

See the graphs on slide 33.

Derivation of the Lerner Index

Marginal revenue is strongly related to the price elasticity of demand, which is \(E_{D}=\frac{\Delta q}{\Delta p} \times \frac{p}{q}\)1

We derived marginal revenue (in the slides) as:

\[MR(q)=p+\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}q\]

Firms will always maximize profits where:

\[\begin{align*} MR(q)&=MC(q) && \text{Profit-max output condition}\\ p+\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\bigg)q&=MC(q) && \text{Definition of } MR(q)\\ p+\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\bigg) q \times \frac{p}{p}&=MC(q) && \text{Multiplying the left by } \frac{p}{p} \text{ (i.e. 1)}\\ p+\underbrace{\bigg(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q}\times \frac{q}{p} \bigg)}_{\frac{1}{\epsilon}} \times p &=MC(q) && \text{Rearranging the left}\\ p+\frac{1}{\epsilon} \times p &=MC(q) && \text{Recognize price elasticity } \epsilon=\frac{\Delta q}{\Delta p} \times \frac{p}{q}\\ p &=MC(q) - \frac{1}{\epsilon} p && \text{Subtract }\frac{1}{\epsilon}p \text{ from both sides}\\ p-MC(q) &= -\frac{1}{\epsilon} p && \text{Subtract }MC(q) \text{ from both sides}\\ \frac{p-MC(q)}{p} &= -\frac{1}{\epsilon} && \text{Divide both sides by }p\\ \end{align*}\]

The left side gives us the fraction of price that is markup \(\left(\frac{p-MC(q)}{p}\right)\), and the right side shows this is inversely related to price elasticity of demand.

Firms With Market Power vs. Competitive Firms’ Responses to Market Changes

Consider a firm in a competitive market (left) and a firm with market power (right):

An Increase in Firms’ Marginal Cost

A competitive firm responds by only changing its output \(q^\star\) (since it cannot control price), whereas the firm with market power changes both its \(p^\star\) and \(q^\star\).

A Shift in Market Demand

Both firms change \(p^\star\) and \(q^\star\), but there is a much smaller change in \(q^\star\) for the monopolist.

A Change in Price Elasticity of Demand

For the competitive market on the left, there is no change in \(q^\star\) or \(p^\star\) for the industry! On the right, the monopolist will lower (raise) \(p^\star\) and raise (lower) \(q^\star\) as demand becomes more (less) elastic!

Footnotes

  1. I sometimes simplify it as \(E_{D}=\frac{1}{slope} \times \frac{p}{q}\), where “slope” is the slope of the inverse demand curve (graph), since the slope is \(\frac{\Delta p}{\Delta q} = \frac{rise}{run}\).↩︎

Content 2022 by Ryan Safner
All content licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution-NonCommercial 4.0 International license (CC BY-NC 4.0)
Made with and Quarto
View the source at GitHub