See my game theory course for more
There's a lot more to game theory than a one-shot prisoners' dilemma:
one shot vs. repeated game
discrete vs. continuous strategies
perfect vs. imperfect vs. incomplete/asymmetric information
simultaneous vs. sequential games
We use various “solution concepts” to allow us to predict an equilibrium of a game
Nash Equilibrium is the primary solution concept
Recall, Nash Equilibrium: no players want to change their strategy given what everyone else is playing
N.E. ≠ the “best” or optimal outcome
Game may have multiple N.E.
Game may have no N.E. (in “pure” strategies)
1) Cell-by-Cell Inspection: look in each cell, does either player want to deviate?
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 1's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 2's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
N.E.: each player is playing a best response
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Two Nash equilibria again: (A,A) and (B,B)
But here (A,A) ≻ (B,B)!
Path Dependence: early choices may affect later ability to choose or switch
Lock-in: the switching cost of moving from one equilibrium to another becomes prohibitive
Suppose we are currently in equilibrium (B,B)
Inefficient lock-in:
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Perfect competition: no firm wants to raise or lower price given the market price ✓
Monopolist maximizes π by setting q∗: MR=MC and p∗=Demand(q∗)
This is an equilibrium, but is it the only equilibrium?
We've assumed just a single player in the model
What about potential competition?
Incumbent which sets its price pI
Entrant decides to stay out or enter the market, setting its price pE
Suppose both firms have identical costs: C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c
† For arbitrary ϵ>0, think ϵ= “one penny”
Case I: Suppose both firms have identical costs: C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c
† For arbitrary ϵ>0, think ϵ= “one penny”
Nash Equilibrium: (pI=c, Stay Out )
A market with a single firm, but the competitive outcome!
Case II: What if the Entrant has higher costs than the Incumbent: cE>cI?
Nash equilibrium: (pI=cE−ϵ, Stay Out )
One firm again, with some inefficiency
Markets are contestable if:
Generalizes "prefect competition" model in more realistic way, also game-theoretic
William Baumol
(1922--2017)
"This means that...an incumbent, even if he can threaten retaliation after entry, dare not offer profit-making opportunities to potential entrants because an entering firm can hit and run, gathering in the available profits and departing when the going gets rough."
Baumol, William, J, 1982, "Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure," American Economic Review, 72(1): 1-15
Regulation & antitrust (once) focus(ed) on number of firms
Perfect competition as “gold standard”, only market arrangement that is socially efficient:
But number of firms is endogenous and can evolve over time!
A more dynamic situation: firms respond over time
Perfect competition not the only socially efficient market-structure
Regulation and antitrust should consider whether a market is contestable, not just the number of firms
Firms engaging in egregious monopolistic behavior (↓q, ↑p>MC, π>0) largely persist because of barriers to entry
Business activities or political dealings with the goal to raise cE>cI
"Of far greater concern to Microsoft is the competition from new and emerging technologies, some of which are currently visible and others of which certainly are not. This array of known, emerging, and wholly unknown competitors places enormous pressure on Microsoft to price competitively and innovate aggressively." (Schmalensee 1999)
In perfect competition (model):
This is a tendency only because of free entry and exit
Don't judge real markets by their similarity to the perfect competition model
Judge them more on their level of contestability, look for barriers to entry
“All models are wrong, but some are useful” — George Box
"...In that Empire, the Art of Cartography attained such Perfection that the map of a single Province occupied the entirety of a City, and the map of the Empire, the entirety of a Province. In time, those Unconscionable Maps no longer satisfied, and the Cartographers Guilds struck a Map of the Empire whose size was that of the Empire, and which coincided point for point with it. The following Generations, who were not so fond of the Study of Cartography as their Forebears had been, saw that that vast Map was Useless... — Suarez Miranda, Viajes de varones prudentes, Libro IV, Cap. XLV, Lerida, 1658"
Jorge Luis Borges, 1946, On Exactitude in Science
Agents have objectives they value
Agents face constraints
Make tradeoffs to maximize objectives within constraints
Agents have objectives they value
Agents face constraints
Make tradeoffs to maximize objectives within constraints
Agents compete with others over scarce resources
Agents adjust behaviors based on prices
Stable outcomes when adjustments stop
Caution: Two types of (advanced) mistakes:
Believing the model accurately describes reality (100%) and ignoring the model’s flaws
Believing the model is ideal, and reality should be corrected to better match the model
I know you most of you took this class as a business requirement...
...and will forget all the advanced tools in under a week
They were/are meant to familiarize you with how economists model the world
If you ever need to solve a problem, they are a tool may apply
Even if you aren’t going to be an economist, remember:
People respond to incentives
We all have to face tradeoffs (including in politics)
Everyone makes choices on the margin
People tend to adjust to each other towards a (predictable) equilibrium
Incentives and institutions matter (beware the nirvana fallacy)
Role of (potential) competition (over time) & free entry
Markets are a discovery process via prices, profit & loss
Beware, rent-seeking is everywhere and cleverly hidden
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
See my game theory course for more
There's a lot more to game theory than a one-shot prisoners' dilemma:
one shot vs. repeated game
discrete vs. continuous strategies
perfect vs. imperfect vs. incomplete/asymmetric information
simultaneous vs. sequential games
We use various “solution concepts” to allow us to predict an equilibrium of a game
Nash Equilibrium is the primary solution concept
Recall, Nash Equilibrium: no players want to change their strategy given what everyone else is playing
N.E. ≠ the “best” or optimal outcome
Game may have multiple N.E.
Game may have no N.E. (in “pure” strategies)
1) Cell-by-Cell Inspection: look in each cell, does either player want to deviate?
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 1's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Player 2's best responses
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
N.E.: each player is playing a best response
2) Best-Response Analysis: take the perspective of each player. If the other player plays a particular strategy, what is your strategy(s) that gets you the highest payoff?
Two Nash equilibria again: (A,A) and (B,B)
But here (A,A) ≻ (B,B)!
Path Dependence: early choices may affect later ability to choose or switch
Lock-in: the switching cost of moving from one equilibrium to another becomes prohibitive
Suppose we are currently in equilibrium (B,B)
Inefficient lock-in:
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Now that we understand Nash equilibrium...
Are outcomes of other market structures Nash equilibria?
Perfect competition: no firm wants to raise or lower price given the market price ✓
Monopolist maximizes π by setting q∗: MR=MC and p∗=Demand(q∗)
This is an equilibrium, but is it the only equilibrium?
We've assumed just a single player in the model
What about potential competition?
Incumbent which sets its price pI
Entrant decides to stay out or enter the market, setting its price pE
Suppose both firms have identical costs: C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c
† For arbitrary ϵ>0, think ϵ= “one penny”
Case I: Suppose both firms have identical costs: C(q)=cqMC(q)=c
If Incumbent sets pI>c
† For arbitrary ϵ>0, think ϵ= “one penny”
Nash Equilibrium: (pI=c, Stay Out )
A market with a single firm, but the competitive outcome!
Case II: What if the Entrant has higher costs than the Incumbent: cE>cI?
Nash equilibrium: (pI=cE−ϵ, Stay Out )
One firm again, with some inefficiency
Markets are contestable if:
Generalizes "prefect competition" model in more realistic way, also game-theoretic
William Baumol
(1922--2017)
"This means that...an incumbent, even if he can threaten retaliation after entry, dare not offer profit-making opportunities to potential entrants because an entering firm can hit and run, gathering in the available profits and departing when the going gets rough."
Baumol, William, J, 1982, "Contestable Markets: An Uprising in the Theory of Industry Structure," American Economic Review, 72(1): 1-15
Regulation & antitrust (once) focus(ed) on number of firms
Perfect competition as “gold standard”, only market arrangement that is socially efficient:
But number of firms is endogenous and can evolve over time!
A more dynamic situation: firms respond over time
Perfect competition not the only socially efficient market-structure
Regulation and antitrust should consider whether a market is contestable, not just the number of firms
Firms engaging in egregious monopolistic behavior (↓q, ↑p>MC, π>0) largely persist because of barriers to entry
Business activities or political dealings with the goal to raise cE>cI
"Of far greater concern to Microsoft is the competition from new and emerging technologies, some of which are currently visible and others of which certainly are not. This array of known, emerging, and wholly unknown competitors places enormous pressure on Microsoft to price competitively and innovate aggressively." (Schmalensee 1999)
In perfect competition (model):
This is a tendency only because of free entry and exit
Don't judge real markets by their similarity to the perfect competition model
Judge them more on their level of contestability, look for barriers to entry
“All models are wrong, but some are useful” — George Box
"...In that Empire, the Art of Cartography attained such Perfection that the map of a single Province occupied the entirety of a City, and the map of the Empire, the entirety of a Province. In time, those Unconscionable Maps no longer satisfied, and the Cartographers Guilds struck a Map of the Empire whose size was that of the Empire, and which coincided point for point with it. The following Generations, who were not so fond of the Study of Cartography as their Forebears had been, saw that that vast Map was Useless... — Suarez Miranda, Viajes de varones prudentes, Libro IV, Cap. XLV, Lerida, 1658"
Jorge Luis Borges, 1946, On Exactitude in Science
Agents have objectives they value
Agents face constraints
Make tradeoffs to maximize objectives within constraints
Agents have objectives they value
Agents face constraints
Make tradeoffs to maximize objectives within constraints
Agents compete with others over scarce resources
Agents adjust behaviors based on prices
Stable outcomes when adjustments stop
Caution: Two types of (advanced) mistakes:
Believing the model accurately describes reality (100%) and ignoring the model’s flaws
Believing the model is ideal, and reality should be corrected to better match the model
I know you most of you took this class as a business requirement...
...and will forget all the advanced tools in under a week
They were/are meant to familiarize you with how economists model the world
If you ever need to solve a problem, they are a tool may apply
Even if you aren’t going to be an economist, remember:
People respond to incentives
We all have to face tradeoffs (including in politics)
Everyone makes choices on the margin
People tend to adjust to each other towards a (predictable) equilibrium
Incentives and institutions matter (beware the nirvana fallacy)
Role of (potential) competition (over time) & free entry
Markets are a discovery process via prices, profit & loss
Beware, rent-seeking is everywhere and cleverly hidden