+ - 0:00:00
Notes for current slide
Notes for next slide

1.3 — Preferences

ECON 306 • Microeconomic Analysis • Fall 2022

Ryan Safner
Associate Professor of Economics
safner@hood.edu
ryansafner/microF22
microF22.classes.ryansafner.com

Preferences

Preferences I

  • Which bundles are preferred over others?

Example: Between two bundles of (x,y):

a=(4,12) or b=(6,12)

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: (Strictly) prefer a over b

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: (Strictly) prefer a over b

  2. ab: (Strictly) prefer b over a

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: (Strictly) prefer a over b

  2. ab: (Strictly) prefer b over a

  3. ab: Indifferent between a and b

Preferences II

  • We will allow three possible answers:
  1. ab: (Strictly) prefer a over b

  2. ab: (Strictly) prefer b over a

  3. ab: Indifferent between a and b

  • Preferences are a list of all such comparisons between all bundles

See appendix in today's class page for more.

Indifference Curves

Mapping Preferences Graphically I

  • For each bundle, we now have 3 pieces of information:

    • amount of x
    • amount of y
    • preference compared to other bundles
  • How to represent this information graphically?

Mapping Preferences Graphically II

  • Cartographers have the answer for us

  • On a map, contour lines link areas of equal height

  • We will use “indifference curves” to link bundles of equal preference

Mapping Preferences Graphically III

2-D Indifference Curve Contours

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2
    • Apts that are larger and/or have more friends A

Indifference Curves: Example

Example: Suppose you are hunting for an apartment. You value both the size of the apartment and the number of friends that live nearby.

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2
    • Apts that are larger and/or have more friends A
    • Apts that are smaller and/or have fewer friends A

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • B has more friends but less ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • B has more friends but less ft2

  • C has still more friends but less ft2

Indifference Curves: Example

Example:

  • Apt. A has 1 friend nearby and is 1,200 ft2

  • B has more friends but less ft2

  • C has still more friends but less ft2

  • ABC: on same indifference curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

  • Apts above curve are preferred over apts on curve

    • DABC
    • On a higher curve

Indifference Curves: Example

  • Indifferent between all apartments on the same curve

  • Apts above curve are preferred over apts on curve

    • DABC
    • On a higher curve
  • Apts below curve are less preferred than apts on curve
    • EABC
    • On a lower curve

Curves Never Cross!

  • Indifference curves can never cross: preferences are transitive
    • If I prefer AB, and BC, I must prefer AC

Curves Never Cross!

  • Indifference curves can never cross: preferences are transitive

    • If I prefer AB, and BC, I must prefer AC
  • Suppose two curves crossed:

    • AB
    • BC
    • But C B!
    • Doesn't make sense (not transitive)!

Marginal Rate of Substitution

Marginal Rate of Substitution I

  • If I find another apt with 1 fewer friend nearby, how many more ft2 would you need to keep you satisfied?

Marginal Rate of Substitution I

  • If I find another apt with 1 fewer friend nearby, how many more ft2 would you need to keep you satisfied?

  • Marginal Rate of Substitution (MRS): rate at which you trade away one good for more of the other and remain indifferent

  • Think of this as the relative value you place on good x:

“I am willing to give up (MRS) units of y to consume 1 more unit of x and stay satisfied.”

Marginal Rate of Substitution II

Marginal Rate of Substitution II

  • MRS = slope of the indifference curve

MRSx,y=ΔyΔx=riserun

  • Amount of y given up for 1 more x

  • Note: slope (MRS) changes along the curve!

MRS vs. Budget Constraint Slope

  • Budget constraint (slope) from before measured the market’s tradeoff between x and y based on market prices

  • MRS here measures your personal evaluation of x vs. y based on your preferences

  • Foreshadowing: what if these two rates are different? Are you truly optimizing?

Utility

So Where are the Numbers?

  • Long ago (1890s), utility considered a real, measurable, cardinal scale

  • Utility thought to be lurking in people's brains

    • Could be understood from first principles: calories, water, warmth, etc
  • Obvious problems

“Neuroeconomics” & cognitive scientists are re-attempting a scientific approach to measure utility

Utility Functions?

  • More plausibly infer people's preferences from their actions!

    • “Actions speak louder than words”
  • Principle of Revealed Preference: if a person chooses x over y, and both are affordable, then they must prefer xy

  • Flawless? Of course not. But extremely useful approximation!

    • People tend not to leave money on the table

Utility Functions!

  • A utility function u() represents preference relations (,,)

  • Assign utility numbers to bundles, such that, for any bundles a and b: abu(a)>u(b)

The is a placeholder for whatever goods we are considering (e.g. x, y, burritos, lattes, etc)

Utility Functions, Pural I

Example: Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)

Utility Functions, Pural I

Example: Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)

  • Let u() assign each bundle a utility of:
u()
u(a)=1
u(b)=2
u(c)=3

Utility Functions, Pural I

Example: Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)

  • Let u() assign each bundle a utility of:
u()
u(a)=1
u(b)=2
u(c)=3
  • Does this mean that bundle c is 3 times the utility of a?

Utility Functions, Pural II

Example: Imagine three alternative bundles of (x,y): a=(1,2)b=(2,2)c=(4,3)

  • Now consider a 2nd function v():
u() v()
u(a)=1 v(a)=3
u(b)=2 v(b)=5
u(c)=3 v(c)=7

Utility Functions, Pural III

  • Utility numbers have an ordinal meaning only, not cardinal

  • Both are valid utility functions:

    • u(c)>u(b)>u(a)
    • v(c)>v(b)>v(a)
    • because cba
  • Only the ranking of utility numbers matters!

See the Mathematical Appendix in Today's Class Page for why.

Utility Functions and Indifference Curves I

  • Two tools to represent preferences: indifference curves and utility functions

  • Indifference curve: all equally preferred bundles same utility level

  • Each indifference curve represents one level (or contour) of utility surface (function)

Utility Functions and Indifference Curves II

2-D Indifference Curve Contours: y=u2x

Marginal Utility

MRS and Marginal Utility I

  • Recall: marginal rate of substitution MRSx,y is slope of the indifference curve

    • Amount of y given up for 1 more x
  • How to calculate MRS?

    • Recall it changes (not a straight line)!
    • We can calculate it using something from the utility function

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

Marginal utility of x: MUx=Δu(x,y)Δx

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption

Marginal utility of x: MUx=Δu(x,y)Δx

Marginal utility of y: MUy=Δu(x,y)Δy

MRS and Marginal Utility II

  • Marginal utility: change in utility from a marginal increase in consumption
  • Math (calculus): “marginalderivative with respect to

MUx=u(x,y)x

  • I will always derive marginal utility functions for you

MRS and Marginal Utility: Example

Example: For an example utility function:

u(x,y)=x2+y3

  • Marginal utility of x: MUx=2x
  • Marginal utility of y: MUy=3y2
  • Again, I will always derive marginal utility functions for you

MRS Equation and Marginal Utility

  • Relationship between MU and MRS:

ΔyΔxMRS=MUxMUy

“I am willing to give up MUxMUy units of y to consume 1 more unit of x and stay satisfied.”

Important Insights About Value

“I am willing to give up MUxMUy units of y to consume 1 more unit of x and stay satisfied.”

  • We can't measure MU's, but we can measure MRSx,y and infer the ratio of MU's!
    • Example: if MRSx,y=5, a unit of good x gives 5 times the marginal utility of good y at the margin

Important Insights About Value

  • Value is subjective

    • Each of us has our own preferences that determine our ends or objectives
    • Choice is forward looking: a comparison of your expectations about opportunities
  • Preferences are not comparable across individuals

    • Only individuals know what they give up at the moment of choice

Important Insights About Value

  • Value inherently comes from the fact that we must make tradeoffs
    • Making one choice means having to give up pursuing others!
    • The choice we pursue at the moment must be worth the sacrifice of others! (i.e. highest marginal utility)

Diminishing Marginal Utility

The Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility: each marginal unit of a good consumed tends to provide less marginal utility than the previous unit, all else equal

  • As you consume more x:
    • MUx
    • MRSx,y: willing to give up fewer units of y for x

Special Case: Substitutes

Example: Consider 1-Liter bottles of coke and 2-Liter bottles of coke

  • Always willing to substitute between Two 1-L bottles for One 2-L bottle

  • Perfect substitutes: goods that can be substituted at same fixed rate and yield same utility

  • MRS1L,2L=0.5 (a constant!)

Special Case: Complements

Example: Consider hot dogs and hot dog buns

  • Always consume together in fixed proportions (in this case, 1 for 1)

  • Perfect complements: goods that can be consumed together in same fixed proportion and yield same utility

  • MRSH,B= ?

Cobb-Douglas Utility Functions

  • A very common functional form in economics is Cobb-Douglas

u(x,y)=xayb

  • Extremely useful, you will see it often!
    • Lots of nice, useful properties (we'll see later)
    • See the appendix in today's class page

Practice

Example: Suppose you can consume apples (a) and broccoli (b), and earn utility according to:

u(a,b)=2abMUa=2bMUb=2a

  1. Put a on the horizontal axis and b on the vertical axis. Write an equation for MRSa,b.

  2. Would you prefer a bundle of (1,4) or (2,2)?

  3. Suppose you are currently consuming 1 apple and 4 broccoli. a. How many units of broccoli are you willing to give up to eat 1 more apple and remain indifferent? b. How much more utility would you get if you were to eat 1 more apple?

  4. Repeat question 3, but for when you are consuming 2 of each good.

Paused

Help

Keyboard shortcuts

, , Pg Up, k Go to previous slide
, , Pg Dn, Space, j Go to next slide
Home Go to first slide
End Go to last slide
Number + Return Go to specific slide
b / m / f Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode
c Clone slideshow
p Toggle presenter mode
t Restart the presentation timer
?, h Toggle this help
oTile View: Overview of Slides
Esc Back to slideshow